字幕表 動画を再生する 英語字幕をプリント (laughs) (mumbles) - Good evening and welcome to the John F. Kennedy Junior Forum. My name is Remington Hill and I'm a junior, studying Economics and African American studies here at the college and I'm also a member of the JFK Junior Forum Committee here at the Institute of Politics. Before we begin, please note the exit doors which are located on both the park side and the JFK street sides of the forum. In the event of an emergency, walk to the exit closest to you and congregate in the JFK park. Please also take a moment now to silence your cell phones. You can join the conversation tonight online by tweeting with the hashtag Big Econ Ideas, which is also listed in your program. Please take your seats now and join me in welcoming our guests, Oren Cass, Derrick Hamilton, Will Wilkinson, Annie Lawrie by video call and tonight's moderator, Jason Furman. (applause) - Thanks to everyone for joining us and Annie Laurie from the Atlantic. Thanks to you for being here and you will say something and hopefully we'll know you're here. - [Annie] Yeah, can you hear me? - I can hear you great. We also have, Derrick Hamilton, who's currently at the new school. He's about to be the director of the Cowen Center for Race and Ethnicity at Ohio State, Oren Cass who's at the Manhattan Institute, which is a pro market. - Free market. - Free Market think tank and Will Wilkinson who is from a moderate libertarian leaning think tank, the Niskanen Center and all four of these people are big thinkers about big ideas about how to change our economy. And I find in universities, often we're really good at finding the problems and everything and that leads us to have a harder time thinking outside of the box about some of the bigger ways you could have change. But some of the bigger ways to have change can also have problems. The world today works okay. You try to do something big, you might mess up and make it much worse. So what we want to do today is put some of these ideas down on the table try to better understand them and also see what themes come out of them. And also, I should've done this advertising when I was telling people. Annie is on the screen and so it's only fair that her book is on the screen, Give People Money. She will do a slightly longer version of what Give People Money is to lead us off. And then Oren Cass is the author of the forthcoming, Once And Future Worker and I should say, I read both Annie and Oren's books. I think they're both terrific reads, really provocative and both of them made me change my mind on some issues that I'd thought about, thought I had thought about quite a lot which is about the best a book can do. So Annie, why don't you start us off with your big idea. - Yeah, absolutely. So the idea of a universal basic income is a really simple one, which is that the government gives everybody money and it's one that has not been undertaken thus far by at least any big government but a lot of lower and middle income countries have sort of related policies. And so just want to expand on the argument for doing it here in the United States because it sounds at first blush kind of crazy, right? Like, why should the government gives everybody money? Wouldn't people stop working? Aren't there more efficient ways of providing support for low income families? And so, the argument basically is this one. One is that the United States tolerates and in fact structures its safety net to allow a tremendous amount of poverty. Part of the reason that we have that is that many of the support programs that we have have fairly complicated requirements. They make you jump through a lot of hoops to get them, they make sure that you are a very certain type of person in order to receive aid but even with all that, some of the people that are deemed sort of socially important to take care of such as children, nevertheless have very high poverty rates. So that's one argument for doing it. The second is actually kind of a libertarian argument which is that if you just give people cash, they tend to spend it pretty well. They by and large don't actually stop working or if they do, they tend to do so for sort of socially beneficial reasons such as waiting longer for a job match to become employed, staying in school longer, taking care of a kid. So we don't worry about that too much and it's pretty easy for the government and low overhead for the government to just give out cash. There's also the argument that the government should kind of butt out of people's lives and trust them to do with the money what they would like versus something like a housing voucher or food stamps where in some cases, you see people actually trade those in, in the case of food stamps because what they really need is gas to put in their car or money to keep the lights on. And then I think that there's a broader argument to be made that in an economy as rich as the United States is that you do just want to have a universal guarantee for people. A lot of times, there is no currently no form of sort of social insurance that helps people kind of regardless of circumstance, save for income and this would provide that. It would arguably encourage things like entrepreneurship. It would help people and sort of unusual, but nevertheless quite common circumstances such as if you needed to leave a bad housing situation or if you were in an abusive relationship. So I wrote a whole book on it but I'll stop there and I'm very interested to hear all of our other big ideas from our big thinkers. - Great. Thank you Annie. So Derrick is the co developer of the leading or one of the leading federal jobs guarantee programs. So tell us about that. - I guess co-develop with Sandy Darity at Duke University, Mark Paul, let me give shout out to other people real quick. Elena Ha, Daniel Bustillo, Kaiser, Ofrono Mobial and then special shout out Policy Link, Angel Blackwell and Sarah Trehalf. So the idea of a federal job guarantee is not new nodes at radical. President Roosevelt cold for economic bill of rights and the first thing that he called for was the right to guaranteed employment. Unfortunately, since the Nixon administration, the political sentiment regarding social mobility has radically shifted from government mandates of economic security to a neo liberal approach that where the market is presumed to be the solution for all our problems, economic or otherwise. As a result, the onus of social mobility has shifted onto the individual. Pervasive in the implicit on federal markets is the ideas that the virtue of the free market, you can turn your proverbial rags into riches. In other words, the deserving poor who end up poor, they're stigmatized by the political fodder of anti-blackness, whether they're black or not. They receive their just rewards and they simply fade away or have to do something else over time. But the private sector alone has never been adequate to deal with reinforcing inequalities. Over the last 45 years all the gains from American's productivity, have gone to the elite while real worker wages have remained roughly flat. Even those that have a job, 44% of them are homeless, 40% of them working contingent jobs, and 44% have earned below $15 an hour. Jobs stimulates plans championed on both sides of the aisle, they use tax incentives and deregulation to cajole a bribe and already record profit earning private sector to create more jobs under the whimsical notion of trickle down economics. Or if we encourage them to build our infrastructure, that could lead to a transfer value of our public infrastructure onto corporate interests. Instead we favor of federal job guarantee which is a direct source to deal with unemployment and it provides a stimulus effect to stimulate a panopy of activity in the economy. It would enable all workers, particularly those at the low end to bargain for better wages and benefits without the fear and threat of destitution from unemployment. A federal job guarantee would eliminate working poverty altogether, it would eliminate involuntary unemployment, it would address cyclical unemployment as well as structural unemployment and it would provide public options of employment to better enable existing workers to bargain for decent wages, working conditions, again, without that fear of being destitute from unemployment. Our job creation plan provides direct competition to the private sector, particularly at the low end of the market. It's not an employer of last resort program. So rather than subsidizing low wage work, we will raise the floor on wages and benefits through competitive alternative to precarious work. We will structurally change the US economy away from low wage work. We say that's a feature, not a flaw. Moreover, it will provide the best buffer against the threat of oncoming automation which might lead to employment transitions due to technical change. We are not promoting welfare to work but rather we're talking about an authentic right to work. The jobs had reigned from construction, education, health services, supportive housing, libraries, child and elder care, arts and culture, projects designed to transform our cities to green municipalities that are emission free and sustainable and resilient. The work could also address disability interest so that we are able to not only employ people that are designated as disabled, but empower them so that they can be more independent in their living. The federal government states, Indian nations, local municipalities, community councils, they all could conduct inventories of their needs and develop a job bank of task in which we will prioritize those communities that are in the most need, as well as provide stimulus to those communities that are in most need. A job guarantee would mitigate the personal familiar course demand from damaged mental health, having workers out of work does emit damage to the human spirit. The unemployed themselves, say they would rather work than receive a subsidy. Dignity is multifaceted. One's dignity is not limited to work, but everyone should have the right to work with dignity of at least decent wages, benefits and good working conditions. - Okay, great. An alternative also focused on work is Oren on wage subsidies. - Yeah, thank you guys very much for coming. I guess I want to talk about a big economic idea, bolting conceptual and sort of substantive policy terms because I think it's helpful as you hear all of these ideas to think about which visions of prosperity we're actually banking on and trying to make things better. So the big idea and this goes a little bit to what we just heard as well is that work is what matters. That when we're looking at our prosperity as a society, what really matters is that people can find productive work to do and that they can through that work support their families and their communities. And on the one hand that sounds like common sense. On the other hand, it is dramatically divergent from the economic policy we've actually pursued, which is almost exclusively focused on consumer welfare. We're going to grow the economic pie. Everyone can have a larger slice and we don't really care too much about who baked the pie to stretch the metaphor a little bit too far. So if we say that work matters and that the real key to our prosperity isn't just going to be more pie for everybody, it's actually going to be jobs that everyone, regardless of their abilities, regardless of where they are can use to support their families and their communities, then we're going to need some policies to support that because there's nothing in economics that says the labor market is going to land there on its own. The policy that I'm very interested in is what's called a wage subsidy which is in its simplest terms, direct additional money from the government in your paycheck. So the easiest way to think of this is just like right now we have payroll taxes. And from your first dollar, you've got that line called Fica in your check. Any Friends fans, Rachel Green gets her first paycheck from the coffee shop, opens it up and says who's Fica and why's he taking all my money? We tax actually quite heavily even waitresses at coffee shops. We could just as easily do the reverse. We could have a line in that paycheck that says work credit and it could be additional money in the paycheck, particularly for people with low wages. Now we have something along these lines already called the earned income tax credit or EITC. The way the EITC works is at the end of the year when you file your taxes, if you're of a certain kind of household, typically if you have kids, if you're in a certain earnings range, you get a big chunk of money up to five or $6,000. That certainly helps households. It is not a great way to actually make jobs look attractive in the moment. It's not a great way to deliver money to people regularly in a way that's going to meet their financial needs and what you find is typically workers either aren't really aware of what it is or how much they're going to get. And conversely, actually once they do receive it, first of all, they use it to pay overdue bills, which isn't the right structure for earning and actually you also see a lot of people exit the labor force because they just got this windfall. So the key is to shift this, first of all, let's not just focus it on families with kids, which is where almost all the money goes today. Let's just focus on the worker and if you're a low wage worker, let's say that you're eligible for the same amount and then let's put it in every paycheck. And so what would happen is it would literally just be a function of your hourly wage. You would pick a target wage. Let's say we pick something around $15 an hour and if you're a market wage is below that, we're going to make up half the difference with a subsidy. So your eight-dollar an hour job, seven dollars less than 15, so you get a 3.50 subsidy. It's now $11.50 an hour job in every paycheck. A $10 an hour job, five dollars off, so you get to $2.50. It's now $12.50 an hour job. And obviously that phases out. So by the time you are at 15 or above, you're not getting a subsidy anymore. This would be transparent to the worker, you'd see in the paycheck what you're getting. It would also be saying that therefore could be advertised when you're marketing a job. You could say, look, this is what the job is going to pay inclusive of the subsidy, which I think will be important both in encouraging employers to create an offer of the jobs ended encouraging workers on the margins of the workforce to take them. And then obviously the last question is how you pay for it. A big part of the answer is we actually already have a massive safety net that redistributes more than a trillion dollars a year, typically through programs that either ignore work entirely or actually discourage work because we take the benefit away if you start working. So I think the best thing to do would just be to take a share of this. For the program I'm describing, you would use about 200 billion out of the trillion and say we're now going to make promoting work actually a significant part of the safety net. And so we're not shrinking the total amount of support we give to low income households but those benefits that look like food stamps, housing vouchers are really going to be concentrated on people who aren't working and if you are someone who's working, you're actually going to get that support in the form of cash, which as Annie described, is really what people want most and is a way to make the benefit more valuable. - Great. Will, I haven't even read your idea. So I'm in as much suspense as everyone else. - Well, thank you. I hope it's worth the surprise. And it's an honor to be included in such a gust company. I'm going to start out by just asking a question for everybody. Raise your hand if you think you pay too much for rent or your mortgage. We got a lot of students. I think most of us who live in a big city like Boston or New York or L.A or Chicago are paying way too much. And the reason that property values are so expensive, why mortgages are so high, why rents are so high, is that the supply of housing has not expanded in line with demand for housing. It's pretty simple economics. Now the question gets a lot more complicated once you drill down, but we just have a big mismatch of supply and demand and if a lot more people are chasing a very limited a stock of housing, the prices go up. And why has that happened? There's a lot of reasons, but one of the main reasons is zoning laws or land use policy in cities and other kinds of municipalities. Zoning laws restrict what kinds of buildings can be built in what areas of town. They tell you how many bedrooms a house has to have, how many stories it can be. And over time, over the past 30 years or so, those laws have become much, much, much more restrictive. And they're incredibly damaging along several dimensions. One, housing costs are eating up more and more of people's paychecks. So the percentage of your household budget that goes to housing keeps getting bigger and bigger and bigger and for a lot of people, that means that after they pay for housing, they basically have nothing left to live on. On the flip side of it, people who've got a house back when they were cheaper, are sitting on this quickly appreciating asset. So their wealth is growing. It's ballooning while poor people can't accumulate any wealth at all because they have nothing to save after they pay for their housing. So there's a question of just equity there but there's a bigger comprehensive macro economic problem. Productivity in the economy is driven by the productivity of labor markets and over decades and decades, economic production in the United States has become more and more concentrated in a handful of you know, very big metropolitan areas, just a handful of cities now produces way over half of US GDP. People don't really realize how much of our wealth comes from big cities. Like New York city produces the GDP of Canada, the entire country, right? Boston producers like the GDP of Thailand and when these housing restrictions, when land use restrictions make housing too expensive, it makes it impossible for workers to move to the labor markets where they're most productive. And over time, if you add up millions and millions of workers who would be more productive if they couldn't move to Boston or could be more productive if they moved to Los Angeles or if they moved to New York, if they can't move to the places where they're most productive, the entire economy loses a huge amount of output leaving everybody in the country poor. So there's been a number of economic papers, recently the said that GDP could be massively higher if land use restrictions had remained at about the level of 1980 and the numbers are dramatic. So my proposal is to do something that people think is impossible, but it is, which is incredibly vigorous federal action to deregulate local land use. Now this is one of those issues where people assume that it's a local issue and that there's nothing that the feds can do about it, but that's just wrong. There's a number of things they can do about it. One, you can just directly legislate, to more clearly articulate the content of people's property rights. So congress can just say that, excessive land use restrictions or excessive zoning constitutes a taking, which is in the, what is it? You're the lawyer, the Fifth Amendment, if the government takes your property, they have to give you compensation. And Congress has all the authority it needs to just articulate and refine what it is, what it means to take somebody's property. So that's one thing you can do. Two, the federal government can just flex its power under the Commerce Clause. One of the biggest assets the United States economy has is this giant free mobility zone. We have open borders internally and our labor markets cross state lines and the productivity of the entire economy depends critically on the mobility of workers over this big free labor zone. However, land use restrictions really materially impact that asset that we have. The Commerce Clause says that Congress can regulate interstate commerce if it has a regulate stuff that's happening in a particular place, if it has substantial effect on interstate commerce and this does. Another thing that you can do is just to attach strings on and this is an idea that the one time I've actually articulated it in a Washington post piece, we need a lot of infrastructure upgrades. We need to spend a lot of money on infrastructure. That money tends to go from the federal government to states through big grants for infrastructure, the federal government can tie strings to that and say you don't get this money unless you deregulate local land use. Now tying strings to federal funding is only constitutional if the strings are related to the spending in the right way, but it is in this case because the direct value of infrastructure is directly related to the number of people in these big cities who can use it. So if you dangle a huge pot of money out in front of the states and say, here, California have billions and billions of dollars, but you can only get it if your three biggest cities meet a target in the increase in their housing supply. Say such that the increase in prices don't outpace wage growth, that they like stayed related in the right kind of way, that they're not getting more and more expensive relative to what people have to spend, if you just set that rule and say like, if you don't meet this requirement, you don't get any of this money, well then states will have a big incentive to put the hammer down on municipalities to make sure that they figure out a way to expand their housing stock. That doesn't mean the federal government has to tell them exactly how to do it, it just tells them that they have to do it if they want to get this money. So I think I probably went on too long, but that's the idea. And this doesn't cost anything really, by the way, like so all these ideas costs a lot of money, this doesn't really cost anything, it just releases a latent productivity. - Wanted to do a sort of quick round in reverse order so Will, if we've heard too much from you, now it's gonna get even worse. One or two comments on some of the ideas you've heard, something you like, something you don't like. Don't be comprehensive. And then... - I'll go in order. I like Andy's idea. I'm a proponent of a universal basic income myself. One of the difficult issues with UBI is exactly how you finance it and how big it can be. And so that's one of the biggest questions that people just have about it. What is the size of the sort of minimum guaranteed income and how are you going to finance it? Like you can get a pretty small UBI by rearranging entitlement programs that we already have. But if you want a big one, it's a lot of extra money and so that's just a question, so that's something I'd ask Annie is like how she sees the best way to finance that. I also really like wage subsidies. So I think it's in some ways, just in the menu of policy options, wage subsidies and UBI tend to be in competition for that kind of the same pool of money. And people who like wage subsidies are people who really want to emphasize the importance of work. People who like UBIs really want to emphasize the importance of making sure that everybody has a threshold level of income. So like I guess I'd want to know why you think that a wage subsidy is a better use of money than UBI. A Universal Basic Income it's a guaranteed income floor basically, so everybody would get a certain amount of money every month or every year. And so the question is sort of a big it's going to be? - Oren, what don't you like about UBI and Annie, you're going to go last, you're going to be able to just clean up all the missed statements. - I think Will put it well that the UBI versus wage subsidy debate comes down a lot to how you feel about work and I think it's important to think about it not just in economic terms but cultural ones as well. One thing I will press Annie on is to define what UBI we're exactly talking about because you can sort of get into a shell game where it's affordable if it also phases out and you end up taxing people a lot or you only give it to certain people and if you actually do the full one, that truly just gives everyone enough money to live on, you're truly talking about trillions and trillions of dollars. So first of all, I would say wage subsidy and UBI are not competing for the same pool of money. UBI needs about at least an order of magnitude more and then I think it really comes down to a question of, how we want to find people's obligations and role in society. If you create a UBI, you are effectively moving the basic obligation of supporting yourself and your family from the individual onto the government. From again, from this perspective of the economic pie is big enough, we can give everyone a big enough piece that absolutely appears to solve the problem. If we actually take a view of prosperity, which I do that says no, people feeling like they are fulfilling their own obligation as a productive contributor and supporting a family and that's what gives work meaning in a lot of cases and that in turn is central to their lives and to forming families and to raising kids, then a UBI is actually incredibly destructive and whereas a wage subsidy really promotes that kind of behavior. So that's the distinction that I would draw and you know what I always use the question I posed to folks is just, what would you give a UBI to your own kid? Would you say to your own kid, "I just want you to know, "no matter what you do with your life, "don't worry about it. "You've got 12,000 a year coming, "even if you're smoking pot in the basement "or just going to Europe." And obviously we would not do that, or we would not think highly of parents who took that approach. If you have a UBI, your crazy uncle Sam just came and did that to everybody and there's nothing you can do about it. And I don't think we'd actually want the society that would result. - Why don't we skip to you Annie? - Yeah, so I would know that I don't hate any of these big ideas. They're just a probably an annoying position to have. I would also note that my parents paid an extraordinary amount of money for me to go to Harvard and I spent a lot of time hanging out in a basement smoking pot. (laughing) So those two things are probably not totally my-- - Annie my 11 year old son is here on the front row. - Cover your ears, my apologies. That is totally untrue. - You're teaching him that it's okay to lie. - That as well. I think that there's this funny way in which we have a tremendous amount of government spending which goes to supporting work and that's really great, right? Like the EATC is an enormously successful program, perhaps one of the most successful programs that we have. But nevertheless, we have a lot of people that we leave behind and those are in fact the most vulnerable people, children, people with disabilities, people who are illiterate or have language challenges, people who are in very remote areas. And so I sort of think about UBI as reaching those folks. In terms of the cost question, it's hard, it's an expensive policy. There's probably not enough money to tax among rich people and so you're probably looking at some other type of taxes so, people talk about things like carbon taxes or things like moving towards kind of consumption style, VAT tax, but I would know, we just gave a trillion dollar tax cuts to corporations and to very wealthy individuals. The United States currently taxes and spends about 25% of GDP whereas comparably wealthy countries in Europe it's as much as 15 or 25 percentage points higher. So I think that the money is there. As to the merits of the other idea, we're in I think that the question I would pose to you is how do you make it so that businesses don't just simply take the wage subsidy and subtract it from workers' wages? I'm sure that there is a way to do that perhaps with minimum wage regulation, something like that. And then in terms of the jobs guarantee, I think that there's so many great programs that we've seen, so things like transitional jobs programs that have worked really well or just direct hiring programs during recessions. But it's a really big job to hire, four percent of people during a good economy and 10% of people perhaps even more during a bad economy. And so I'm just curious as to Derrick's thoughts on how you actually achieve that scale, everywhere in the economy because there's also a question of how you do it, not just in sort of cities or places where government services are already co-located but out everywhere. If you're gonna to have it truly be a guarantee. So those are those are two of my questions. - Well Oren we'll get back to you on Annie's question. Derrick why don't you... - To answer your question I'd say that, there are many great things that we can build in terms of our infrastructure. Well imagine literally greening every home in America. How many homes are there in America? How many jobs would that create? Beyond just my imagination, we have historical precedences of the WPA when we leverage larger segments of the labor market to rebuild and build America. We have wars where we've put Americans to work and even outside of America, if we think about promoting world peace, if we start thinking about a marshall plan again, America could literally use its employment resources to reimagine the type of world that we want to live in. So I think the imagination is the only constraint and we certainly can put Americans to work. I'd also say that the plan that I put forth literally eliminates working poverty, literally eliminates involuntary unemployment. Some of my critiques of my colleagues and I'll start with Will is that Will, in my view, came up with a slighter hand. He gave the proposition of New York city and the housing cost in New York city. The rent's too damn high in New York city. The rent is not high. The rent is high because of the market, not in spite of the market. So basically deregulating housing and getting rid of a zoning laws is not gonna make the rent go down it's going to make the rent go up, housing price is gonna go up. Some of the things that they have controlled rents in New York has been things like rent control, for example, so I don't think that'll be the solution. On an ending I don't have big objections to their proposals. My concern would Oren's is that it's still subsidized as low wage work, which might be the problem in and of itself. This is why the federal job guarantee in contrast provides a public alternative to firms that offer low wages, low benefits and poor working conditions. Subsidizing them won't make them go away. We plan to put a floor so that if they want to compete in the market space for labor, they have to offer really good products. Poor people are vulnerable to extraction and exploitation from firms. That's how they make profits. That is their goal. So the policies I'm talking about is a mandated right for empowerment for people and that relates to Annie's policy in the notion of how do we empower people so that they have agency in their lives, so that they can be self determining and make choices for their lives. So I liked the intent around a UBI. I have concerns with the universality of it where everybody gets the same amount and if everybody gets the same amount, the most generous UBI I've seen have been $10,000. Well that doesn't elevate everybody out of poverty. In fact, it could be slightly inflate, it couldn't be not slightly it could be inflationary, but it also might have the unintended consequences of enhancing inequality. If I'm wealthy I can invest. If I'm poor by definition I have to consume. So I like providing people with direct resources, I would only do it in a way where it's not universal, where everybody literally gets the same amount. - So Oren, Annie asked you a question, I want to broaden it a little bit. She asked you the question of you are saying, "Let's go out there and give employers money "and the less they pay their workers, "the more we'll give them." And asking us to accept something that sounds illogical like that. So I want to hear a little bit about that, but I want to hear from you and then from others as well. We teach people about evidence-based policymaking here. You're talking about a really big new program. Would you do this right away for the whole country? Would you pilot it? How would you figure out other than just your own intuition, which is pretty good but not perfect if this works or not? - So I think Annie's question about who ultimately benefits and how to employers respond is certainly an important one. One thing I'd say is we actually have evidence on this question from the earned income tax credit. So at the end of the day, the earned income tax credit is a similar program. We give money to people who are earning low wages and we give more money to people who are earning lower wages. And we have studies of both the US and the UK alternative that show that roughly 70 to 75% of the benefit is typically captured by the worker. Now why would that be the case? If you imagine let's just take Target and Walmart sitting there. They offer whatever wage they offer. If a wage subsidy comes into the market and one or the other of them says, "Well this is great, I'm just going to pocket "the subsidy myself." Well, the other one could just pocket a little bit less and still be better off than they were and attract all of the workers that they want. So to the same extent that you have a competitive labor market without the wage subsidy, you would still expect to have the competitive market with the wage subsidy. And in fact, the only way that the employer, if you kind of do the Econ 101 supply and demand picture, the only way the employer can actually benefit is if the wage subsidy causes supply to increase. So in other words, they need more people to come into the market to allow them to offer a lower market wage and therefore capture some of the benefit for themselves. Well, more people coming into the market is exactly what we want. So employers are only capturing some of this benefit to the extent that we're successful and then it's also important to flip that in your head and recognize that any policy you propose that helps bring more especially less skilled workers back into the labor market, is going to have the same effect. So bringing more or less skilled workers into the labor market is synonymous with doing something that's beneficial not only to the workers but to employers as well. And I'm going to come to your question, second question I just want to say one thing briefly connecting this to Derrick's critique. It's just not true that low wage employers are there to exploit and extract profit from these oppressed workers. Workers in the labor market and the employers who are employing them are engaged in a mutually beneficial transaction, which by the way is pretty hard on the employer side as well. I ask a lot of folks in business schools in particular, how many of you are planning to go out there and create a lot of low wage jobs and build a business that's going to employ a lot of low wage workers and work with them to build their skills. It's not a popular answer. It's typically not the most attractive way to earn a quick return in this economy. And if we actually want an economy built on people working productively at all skill levels, we actually have to be supporting the employers as well and recognize they're providing an important social function and not attack them as oppressors. In terms of how you implement it and how confident we can be, something like the EITC gives us some evidence at the macro level of what we might expect to see. But certainly there are a lot of implementation challenges. The fact that we do the payroll tax and know how to take money out of everybody's paycheck every pay period tells us we also, roughly speaking know how to put money into paychecks every pay period. But it's certainly something where a pilot could make sense. Where you would pick a few labor markets, invite states or municipalities to essentially apply to pilot the program, maybe instead of in lieu of the ITC eligibility in their community and it's worth seeing what problems crop up, how well it works. Senator Rubio actually introduced a very interesting bill to do it in Puerto Rico because this could actually be a very useful tool to help with some of the really unique labor market challenges they face there. So I certainly think testing it before throwing triggered, I wouldn't propose legislation to spend $200,000,000,000 next year, but I think both conceptually and as a construct, it's the right way to move - And Will on land use I strongly agree with you. I think it's a big problem. I think it affects growth, all of that. It doesn't seem entirely illegitimate of people to have views about how their area looks. This doesn't seem like it's obviously wrong as a local policy. Why do you think it is obviously wrong? Second is, do you throw out a lot of benefit of learning? You sort of force something on the whole country at once and you can't have different places experimenting, learning from each other and ending up evolving to a better place that way. - First of all, why do I think it's bad? Effectively, it's just a redistributive policy, right? When I think of restrictive zoning, I think of it like Democrats in cities, they have the same attitude about land use as Republicans have about cutting taxes. It's like I don't wanna pay more in taxes, it's going to gonna support lazy, poor people, it's gonna be wasted by the government. But there's a billion reasons why they want to pay less in taxes, but mostly it's just they want money, right? And don't want it to give it away. When you buy a house and if you can do anything to prevent everybody else from your neighborhood in building another house, the value of your house goes up, right? And you can say and this is what people say, well, I want to defend the traditional historic character of the neighborhood, I want there to be good sight lines, I'm worried that if we build a new big apartment building with apartments that are affordable to middle class people well that will bring a sword into the neighborhood that'll change my... And there's a billion reasons why you can't build more housing and I just see it, it really does just come back to people just want their house to appreciate in value because we've structured our system in an insane way to push people to treat their house as an investment vehicle which is a really bad idea. So there's that. I just think that and then people would just harming other people, like you are literally more productive if you work nearer to more productive people. There are these efficiencies of agglomeration, economists call them and if these restrictions that are implemented largely because people, the way the governance is structured in these towns, like very small groups of people can have a veto right over development. Those people are making it so that it's impossible for millions of other people to move there and earn more. And that seems to me fundamentally illegitimate. - And to super quickly losing the benefit of experimenting and learning from different places. - I don't think there needs to be any certain kind of mandate, so one of the things that I would like you to keep in mind is that I'm not proposing any new regulation. I'm proposing limits on regulation, that if cities want to restrict the property rights of people who own a parcel of land, that has to have a valid regulatory justification it needs to serve some purpose of, it's gotta protect the environment, it's gotta be good for health, it's gotta be good for safety. There's gotta be a reason why you're restricting somebody's right to build a taller building. And that reason has to be real, they can't just be, I say so, which is basically how economic regulation works these days. And so if you have that rationale, if you have a legitimate rationale for restricting how people can dispose their property, that's fine. And within the scope of legitimate regulation of land use, cities are free to do whatever they want. They can prioritize whatever they want, they can do so that it doesn't prevent their experimentation, what it does is just prevents a kind of regulatory maximalism, which is what we're getting, which is what's making city's so expensive and making those housing markets so in affordable. - Want to ask a quick question to Derrick then to Annie, then open it up to all of you. Derrick, Annie raised one concern of the federal jobs guarantee would have to go from small to large. What's the capability of government of doing this wide variety of tasks? Does somebody get trapped in this job and doesn't move into the private sector? Does it crowd out the private sector? There's a whole bunch of criticisms and concerns. I don't want you to try to answer each of those, but want you to answer how we'd figure out whether those were legitimate. And in particular, Senator Booker has proposed I believe it's 15 places to pilot this. Is that how we should start? If I gave you the choice of trying it out on a few places versus trying out everywhere, would you think you have the confidence to go everywhere right away? - So I support Booker's bill about demonstrations, but I would also support a bill that went to full implementation. I think in terms of demonstration, we have historical precedent. That's where I would turn to and right here in this country of being able to mass large segments of the labor force relate for government infrastructure projects that have literally transformed our economy into an efficient economy with well-functioning roads, bridges and I can come up with all types of new infrastructure that we could think about, also human resource infrastructure. So I guess I'm not timid in my belief that we can actually do this. I believe that it's a matter of will rather than being a resident of constraint, of not having enough viable projects that we can actually put together. I'd challenged people in the audience, walk home today and think about all the ways that their lives could be improved if there was some infrastructure in place to improve their lives. I think we really could come up with the idea, so I'm less concerned with that. The issue of crowding out the private sector, that's the intent, right? So a lot of people have critiqued the federal job guarantee and saying that you will do away with low wage work. That is in part the goal. If you are not providing jobs and at adequate wage, if you are not providing benefits and job conditions at an adequate level, then workers will have an alternative. That is part of the point of my critique against Oren. It is literally providing a public option so that workers really can have decency and dignity in the workplace, but it also generates infrastructure that is useful for us. So those are features, not flaws. (mumbles) - I wanted to ask just what, when you kind of described a livable wage and what is this a $15 dollar an hour job with benefits? What's the baseline that we're going to crowd the private sector out at? - So the annual starting wage for a full time worker would be $25,000 and that's equivalent to the poverty line of a family of four. That wouldn't be the only wage. We estimate that the average wage would be about 32,500. In terms of would they be stuck in these jobs? We would even allocate one day a month so that people can do all types of other, either job training or go out and look for jobs. So you'd have one personal day a month where you could try to do personal development to transition into other jobs. And then Annie brought up another point earlier about the federal job guarantee, also about job training programs that have been successful. One thing's for sure. If you have a job training program with no job at the end, that's a problem. So I'm all for job training and things like that but what would it be really good is if we had the assurance that there would be a job waiting for the person at the end. - So Annie, last question is for you. It's actually a little bit broader. How do you think about the trade-off between universality in public programs versus targeting. When targeting saves a lot of money, gets money to people who need it but anyway, how do you think about it? - Yeah. I think that universality is a concept that has to do with this idea of this not being a welfare payment but a social insurance system. Universality guarantees the buy-in of middle income Americans, middle class Americans who tend to be the ones with political power who vote. There's a reason that something like social security has tremendous amount of support in the public, whereas a program like Tanif, which is the cash welfare program is very often maligned. So I think that that's the argument for it. But I think that universality doesn't get rid of the need for progressivity, the need for the government to be giving more to people with less. And that's why we were talking about how this is kind of a really big radical idea, but there are ways to implement it that are way less radical. So Luke Shaffer, who's an economist I think at Michigan and some of his coauthors have a proposal for a guaranteed minimum income. So basically the government knows how much everybody earns. You'd boost everybody up to a certain level thus eliminating poverty. That would cost something like $200 billion a year, a little bit, which is a lot of money but not really anything on the scale of something like a UBI and it would not be universal in the sense that everybody would get it but it would be universal in the sense that it would make sure that everybody was getting above that, that, that poverty line. We've been talking a little bit about trialing and I do think that certainly, when the next recession comes around, there tends to be these bills that have lots of pockets of money to try different things out and I do hope that there's some effort to move towards some kind of cash benefits system to see the kind of trade-offs that it would have. Certainly, I think it's just true that if you're giving everybody the same amount of money, that's not a very efficient way to do things, but there is an argument for it and there are kind of smaller ways to do it that get you a lot bigger bang for the buck. - Great, thank you. So we're opening up to questions now. There are four microphones and as usual, identify yourself, ask a question and that means one thing that ends in a question mark. Starting with you. - [Eloise] You can hear me. Hello, hello. - I think for most of these, unfortunately, why don't you direct them to one person. Everyone's gonna have views on everything but we'll only have time for one person per question. - Okay. I just wanted to say thank you to the panel, to you Dr. Cass, brother Derrick, Annie, Dr. Furman. I think I've said all of you, right? - [Jason] You should just get straight to your question. - Okay. So Derrick, you spoke about infrastructure, economic infrastructure. My name is Eloise Davis. I work at the Center for Public Leadership in HKS. I'm an economist and a business major. So can you speak a little bit about infrastructure when it comes to the other side? So we're talking about you're saying something about roads and good bridges and everything, but it comes down to people and it comes down to people's hearts and what's deep seated inside and the intention and the motivation of the policies, UBI, wage subsidies, but it comes down to the people who make the decisions that affect our lives. You spoke about communities, but our communities, they consist of White, Black, Yellow, Brown, etc. So there wasn't a lot of discussion about how low-wage workers are usually Black and Brown. Can the panel address for me what are the other factors that are involved because to me it seems like considering-- - You know what, why don't we take it from there and have Derrick. That's a big question and give you an opportunity to try to tackle some part of it just in the interest of time. - And also I just want to help if I can help with the next generation if you could tell me what I need to do to connect with you. - So just try to take one piece of that. - So to be clear, we're not talking about workfare. I framed this as part of an economic bill of rights. So we talked about human rights, civil rights. The next frontier is economic rights so that people have a base level of resources. So I share your concerns that you raise. So how do we empower stigmatized populations based on race, former incarceration status, disability status, etc. We literally eliminate involuntary unemployment so they have a right to work, period. An authentic right to work for decent wages and all those other things. And the last part, and I know we're going to move on is a big part of it is not just physical infrastructure but the human infrastructure. So imagine literally providing care work from childhood all the way through elder care. Think about the disproportionate gender effect that will have because usually in our society, unfortunately we relegate that as work for women, which is unpaid and often keeps them out of the labor force to begin with. Let's professional lives, care work altogether. - Great. - Hi, my name is Alex Howlett. I host a weekly basic income discussion and debate meetup group here in Cambridge. My question is for Oren. So it seems like there's three big problems, at least three big problems here. One is how do you get money to consumers? Another is how do you incentivize workers to do the labor that needs to be done in the economy and then how do you provide or how do you ensure that people have meaning and purpose in their lives? So my question to Oren is to what extent do we want to sacrifice efficiency in the labor market, like incentivizing people to do the labor in order to provide these other two things, incomes to consumers and meaning and purpose in people's lives. So that's it. - Yeah, thanks. I think that's a great question and a great way of framing it that we always have this trade-off between efficiency and just about any substantive goal we might want to impose on a market. And in the case of the labor market, I think there is a substantive goal that we want to sacrifice some efficiency for and that's a specific labor market outcome, which is both in terms of having enough jobs available for people regardless of their skill level and also having those jobs generated enough income that they can support a family. So I wouldn't frame it as much in terms of how much consumers have to spend as framing it in terms of making sure that the jobs available in the economy are ones that are going to allow people to support families and feel like they're achieving self sufficiency. - Great. - Hi, my name is Tusha. I have a question for Annie on UBI on the value of work. So it seems like there's a tension between, so I read your book recently. It was excellent. I thought it was a great introduction to the policy and I'm wondering there's tension between you try to talk about the decrease in labor supply from implementing a policy like UBI but at the end you also talk about kind of a bigger picture about whether or not UBI should be used as a way to change the social norms about work being tied to things that are not even financial. Right now a lot of what people have talked about is value to work. Why should we give money to people because everyone knows that having a job is really good for your wellbeing. But I could see UBI as a way to change that. So how do you think about whether UBI is a way to alleviate poverty or to change social norms about the value of work? - Yeah, so it's a really great question and I think that one thing is that very often, people will say that with UBI, people would stop working and just to reiterate a point I made earlier, the idea is that you're not giving people so much money that they would stop working really. Most people, even for $12,000 a year are not going to quit their jobs. Again, when people choose to do that, we have really strong experimental evidence from this, from pilot programs tends to be because they're taking care of a kid, they're staying in school for longer or they're doing something else that's socially beneficial. So some folks think about UBI as being this kind of insurance policy for the future recessions when automation is going to come and take all of our jobs and what are we going to do then. And I do think that in a world where that happened, UBI might not really in some ways be sufficient to keep people happy. People really do like working. Unemployment is enormously traumatic for people and so I think that there's this idea that we haven't talked about, but then I'm kind of obsessed with which is this notion that you want to get to a kind of economy where robots are doing all of the work and people are just consuming lots of leisure and this is sometimes called fully automated luxury communism, which is my favorite idea, but we're really far way away from that. And so, I just think that there are ways to have this kind of universal safety net insurance system that you're not going to utterly erode the foundations of the modern economy and that, yeah, you do provide a buffer and more big recession into the job was recoveries. - Great, thank you. Carrie, do we have time for two more questions do you think? Okay, great. - Hi, my name is Jackson Grigsby and I'm a junior at the college. I just want to ask briefly, Annie what you think about the idea of a carbon tax and dividends just because it seems like more of a culmination of all of the ideas that kind of broader ideas of the left and the right in something that's a little less radical than a universal basic income. - Yeah, so I love this idea and there's actually this group of kind of bipartisan. I know George Schultz is one of them. Republican statement, Republicans and Democrats statement who argued for doing precisely this. I think the issue is that you wouldn't be raising enough money with a carbon tax to provide a true basic income. However, there's probably a lot of arguments for having a carbon tax and for making it more socially palatable by providing the cash that you would raise as a dividend. So I kind of actually think of them as related but different policies that are aimed at different things. We know that this would work perfectly well. The state of Alaska functionally already does this with it's oil dividend. So I think that perhaps it's a great idea, but you should see that not as a way to finance a UBI at least not exclusively so much as maybe if you want to have a carbon tax for the reason of not wanting to completely cook the planet as fast as we're currently doing it, that that's the reason to do that and that, that would be a good way of then, because carbon taxes are ultimately going to hit consumers and so that would be a way of pushing that money back out to people. - Will, you've done work on carbon taxes. Anything to add? - Generally, when you've got an expensive program, people want to come up with an idea about some particular thing that will fund it and generally, I discourage the idea of thinking that you need a particular way to pay for a particular thing. You need if you've got a program that costs money, you need a tax system that raises that money for everything the government is spending. So you want to have like an optimal tax system, whatever that is to raise the revenue that's sufficient for all the outlays that the government's going to do. If you start thinking about programs, like this program is going to be paid for with this tax and this program is going to be paid for with this tax, then you actually end up with a really incredibly stupid tax system that doesn't raise as much revenue as it could and so rates have to be higher in order to fund all this stuff. So just as a general matter, I just discourage the idea of thinking that you have to link a particular tax to a particular spending program. If it would just be better for us to have a VAT and then charge whatever rate is necessary to raise the revenue that we need, then we should do that but we should just have whatever the most efficient tax is and carbon taxes are efficient taxes. It's good to tax externalities. So there's a lot of good reasons to tax carbon. But I wouldn't want to link them too closely. - Great, Bonnie? - Hi, I have a question for Derrick. - [Jason] Oh you could say your full name though. - Bonnie Carvinski. I have a question for Derrick. The federal jobs currency sounds like a very interesting idea and it sounds like it would economically empower a lot of people. I have a question about how you think it would impact entrepreneurship because on the one hand, a lot of people would have a lot more economic security to be able to start businesses, but on the other hand, it would also increase labor costs because employers would have to pay more to hire people and entrepreneurs not to stretch every dollar. So I'm just wondering how you think a jobs guarantee would impact that. - I mean to me the biggest issue with entrepreneurship is capital in the first place. So I think another way to think of this also, if there is no magic bullet, so I think we need a package of products that empower people and if we want to engage entrepreneurship, I think what we really need to do is come up with a system where people have some capital so that they can engage in entrepreneurship. I think that's more of a critical ingredient than the labor part itself, especially for small businesses. So my colleague William Darity and I have talked about baby trust or baby bonds. So just like the right to employment, we think that Americans should have the right to capital. So at birth you would be endowed with some capital regardless of the wealth position that you're born into. So just like somebody who inherits a trust fund to start a business as a birthright, you would have an option with some capital to start a business if you so pleased. - So Annie Dark has had a bunch of chances to give closing remarks and response to questions. If either of you have a 32nd remark to make to close it out. - How things have been briefly I guess in my mind, I think it's important to keep in mind when talking about big ideas that there's the economics of them and the political economy of them and it's important to have big ideas that think boldly and shift what things are going to look like. I worry when the big idea gets to be on the order of taking our taxes as a share of income from 25% to 50% of the economy or a $32,000 a year job guarantee when the median salary in this country is roughly 32,000. We're essentially talking about 60 million workers. And so I do think there's a practicality component that's important that there's a lot we can do with things like wage subsidies. They're going to accomplish our goals but don't throw the baby out with the bathwater and really disrupt the things like about our free market system and a labor market in which people are pursuing work in the private sector as a way to support their families and communities. - Will do have a 32nd? - I just want to give a quote. If people want to find out more about the damage that restrictive land use policy does, I'd like to recommend a book for my colleagues, Steve Teles and Brink Lindsey, it's called The Captured Economy. It's got a wonderful chapter on land use reform as well as the Niskanen Center senior fellow, David Schleicher. He's at Yale law school and has written some great stuff on this. He's got a big Yale Law Review article called Stuck, which helps explain the dynamics of how restrictive land use policy is hurting labor mobility and he's also got a great paper called City on Planning, which gets you inside how the political economy of local zoning politics works, which really brings home how dysfunctional and pathological it is. - Okay. Derrick told me he had his last word. Annie, do you want to take a last word or are you? - I was being polite. (mumbles) - I'm actually okay but I'll turn it back over to you guys. - Okay, great. Derrick, you get the very, very last short, brief word. - Well, two things. One is that to pay for deficits are necessarily bad. It's what those deficits are being spent on that's bad. If they're going to further intrent the plutocracy where the wealthiest reap all the benefits, that's the problem. If deficits are being spent to grow our infrastructure to empower us, that's not necessarily a bad thing. And then the last point is that the dogma that markets are simply efficient, fair, inevitable, I think we need to challenge that. We accept it as a given without critique and that's part of the problem. And what I'm talking about is not doing away with the private sector all together, but rather disciplining the private sector as opposed to disciplining poor people. Let's discipline private sector that if they want to hire poor people, they have to offer jobs with dignity of wages, benefits as well as good working conditions. - Great. Well, I think we've raised a ton of great ideas here. So hope you join me in thanking our four speakers. They all have great books, papers, other things you can pursue to learn more about these topics. So thank you very much for joining us. (applause) Bye Annie. - [Annie] Bye. - Bye Annie.
B1 中級 米 次の大きな経済アイデアとは?UBI、雇用保証、その他の評価 (What s the Next Big Economic Idea? Evaluating UBI, Job Guarantees & Others) 19 0 王惟惟 に公開 2021 年 01 月 14 日 シェア シェア 保存 報告 動画の中の単語