Placeholder Image

字幕表 動画を再生する

  • OK, so we've been talking about information cascades,

  • and analyzing a model of cascades, where people are imitating

  • each other because they're trying to take

  • into account what these other people know.

  • And we've seen a bunch of things about cascades,

  • so they can start quite easily.

  • They can actually be based on very little genuine information--

  • just a few people who do something-- and as a result,

  • they could actually be wrong.

  • A whole bunch of people doing things, and they're all wrong.

  • And they could be fragile.

  • They could be overturned by the infusion of a little bit of extra information,

  • right?

  • So a nice place to think about all of this

  • is with the Wisdom of Crowds argument.

  • The argument roughly is that crowds are smarter than you would expect.

  • And that argument essentially goes that, as long

  • as people don't start off biased.

  • If you have a bunch of people making independent guesses about something,

  • on average they tend to do pretty well.

  • But what happens with cascades is that that can easily get overturned.

  • Because if people are actually observing others' choices sequentially,

  • then as we've seen, the information gets covered up very fast.

  • And you only get information for a few choices.

  • So sometimes crowds can actually be surprisingly

  • dumb rather than surprisingly smart

  • Right, it's sort of like one of these things where, yeah.

  • In one interesting example to think about

  • is a group of people making a decision.

  • You go around the table and you hear what

  • other people, like, what do David think?

  • What do Jon think?

  • And everyone goes around, says what they think.

  • One aspect we didn't think about in a very simple model

  • is which order you put those people.

  • Like should you put the most informed person

  • first or the less informed person first?

  • It's clear to see that the most informed person first, it's sort of tempting.

  • He knows the most, but he's the easiest to start

  • a cascade, because the next guy, being less informed, you're like,

  • maybe I should listen to that guy.

  • So the order-- the cascade story tells us-- what order might be interesting.

  • It might be Interesting to put the people who are not so mal-informed

  • and get them to express their opinions first.

  • And then have people chime in later on.

  • It's one of these funny things where it's really only once-- in fact,

  • actually once we started teaching cascades-- I

  • thought about this experience.

  • And I mean, anyone who's sat in the room,

  • and you've had a discussion going around the table,

  • and you're like, wow that was more unanimous than I thought, right?

  • And you start to appreciate that, maybe not, maybe people are like,

  • oh, well, I guess I had the other opinion,

  • but I guess everyone else must be right, and then they just agree.

  • One of the things you learn from this is that sometimes it's better to have some

  • mechanism [INAUDIBLE] that people have to express their opinion independently

  • first,--

  • Right.

  • --And then have a way to aggregate and have a discussion.

  • But that initial expression of what they believe

  • can be really useful, in ways that actually-- I

  • have to admit-- I'd never thought about either.

  • Even on simple things like these questions like,

  • we're all sitting here trying to figure out how high is Mount Everest, right.

  • There actually is a right answer-- it's about 29,000 feet high,

  • but the first two people go, I think it's about 18,000 feet.

  • Yeah, that sounds right.

  • And then suddenly, there were people in the room who

  • would have been much better, but they give in to the--

  • and so you only got a little bit of.

  • Whereas if everyone could have like-- it's a heavyweight mechanism--

  • that everyone could write down their guess.

  • You fold it up, and if you average, you could actually do really well.

  • Well that was the original Wisdom of Crowds argument.

  • If you had a bunch of independent guesses,

  • it actually surprisingly did turn out pretty well often.

  • It's just that sometimes it gets used in settings

  • where it actually at this point doesn't apply because of this cascade story.

  • So you see this in lots of settings, so this

  • is kind of a micro setting of people sitting around a table or people all

  • guessing.

  • But then you see it like national politics, right?

  • So if we take the US presidential election system anyway,

  • so the party's nominating people and they have state

  • by state primaries that happen over time.

  • So it's sort of perfect for cascades, because the states move in order

  • and so this Iowan, this New Hampshiran, and some candidate

  • gets off to a good start, it's actually this kind of sequential cascade.

  • It's actually a great example because I'm like, go on around the table,

  • where we can choose to ask the most informed or least informed person.

  • The primary [INAUDIBLE] historical order in which they went, New Hampshire

  • is not particularly a big state, but yet it's going first.

  • So in a way, maybe it shouldn't be so influential.

  • It doesn't have so many votes at the final outcome.

  • But yet it's very influential because it's the first state to go.

  • Right, so it becomes this thing where if somebody is successful the first

  • few steps, the cascade might get going.

  • And of course, the whole system conforms around it, so as a result,

  • candidates lavish a ton of attention on New Hampshire

  • residents and Iowa residents.

  • And so in a way they become almost like a focus group.

  • And so maybe that's almost like a self-healing part of the system

  • where they actually invest a lot more energy in it.

  • But it's all because of this notion that they were at the very beginning.

  • But that example also illustrates the fragility of cascades, too.

  • Because if some new information comes along

  • during what would have been a cascade, it

  • seems to be not that hard to overturn it.

  • And that really could be because the cascade actually

  • isn't based on a lot of information anyhow.

  • With the candidates, it's a little harder to tell,

  • but you think back to the simples and models we've had,

  • and you can often have cascades based on just a couple of observations.

  • And so they're actually pretty easy to overturn with some new information.

  • And so you actually consider this thing where someone gets popular,

  • and everyone's like, why is he so popular?

  • And then just evaporates, just suddenly, and because

  • of a little bit of new information.

  • And, I mean, the funny thing, of course, you think like-- I mean all of these

  • have some [INAUDIBLE] design, like if only we could design

  • the right discussion mechanism or primary system.

  • But some of these are very hard to scrap the whole electoral system

  • and do it again.

  • But some things actually just get designed

  • and they could be designed one way or the other.

  • So like, if I think about how people get invited to events, right?

  • Yes--

  • Or parties, right?

  • --Thinking about this evite business.

  • Yeah, so.

  • It's very interesting.

  • Historically, we used to get an invitation

  • and then you either come or not, and you might call up your friends

  • to check, hey Jon, are you coming?

  • And nowadays, people invite this evite and then it's completely public,

  • and you know who is coming and who isn't coming.

  • It's hard to tell what the effect really is.

  • There's some informational effect, but some direct benefit effect

  • that just simply got more information.

  • There's some way the risk cascade because the first few people

  • turned it down, you say eh, that's getting turned down.

  • But you wouldn't have known if it wasn't so public.

  • On the other hand, there is just more information in the system.

  • You simply know who's coming.

  • That's additional information that you simply

  • know that you didn't use to know.

  • And a party is more fun with lots of people,

  • so there's a direct benefit effect.

  • And I guess also-- if you think about the party--

  • once something is established because of a direct benefit effect,

  • now it's hard to overturn.

  • Now it's not fragile anymore.

  • Because suddenly, well, there really are 50 people going to this party,

  • so it will be a fun party, whatever the original plan was, right?

  • In the same way that-- maybe it's accidental

  • that a social networking site gets a zillion people on it,

  • but they're all there now.

  • It really is more valuable.

  • So it's funny that some of these cascades, two cascades

  • get rolling and one of them, you can just sort of knock down really easily.

  • And the other one is really robust now because it sort of locks in it's gains.

  • No, that's a good point.

  • They really can be very different.

  • There can be popularity cascades that aren't necessarily

  • based on much that's real, particularly not much that's a direct benefit,

  • and those are easy to overturn.

  • But the direct benefit ones actually really

  • are hard, even if whatever is succeeding wasn't

  • in some objective-sense the best alternative.

  • Yes.

  • With the direct benefits out there, it actually is better, in fact,

  • than the other alternative because people are using it

  • or because people are doing it.

  • I mean, I feel like it might be sort of almost a strategic aspect to dislike.

  • If you're the owner of a business that got this popularity cascade going,

  • and you're successful, people might come to you with money

  • and advise you, like, it's time to take some steps to kind of make

  • this advantage permanent.

  • To do some things that amplify the direct benefit part of it.

  • Because then, it won't get.

  • That's true, you want to lock your clientele in.

  • However you got them, you want to lock them in now with some kind of benefit.

  • Might be accidental they showed up, but now you

  • want to create the direct benefit effect.

OK, so we've been talking about information cascades,

字幕と単語

ワンタップで英和辞典検索 単語をクリックすると、意味が表示されます

A2 初級

INFO2040X mod5座談会情報カスケードv1 (INFO2040X mod5 roundtable discussion information cascades v1)

  • 58 4
    Jack に公開 2021 年 01 月 14 日
動画の中の単語