字幕表 動画を再生する
Does the structure of capitalism eliminate inequality – or reinforce it?
That is the question at the heart of Capital in the Twenty-First Century,
by the French economist, Thomas Piketty. One of the most discussed academic books published
since the turn of the century, it analyses the role that capitalism plays in global inequality.
For years most economists have believed that capitalism reduces inequality between the
richest and poorest – in the long run. For example, the Kuznets Curve hypothesis suggested
that inequality rises when countries industrialise – but then falls.
Piketty disagrees.
He claims that capitalism creates greater economic inequality.
The Kuznets Curve was constructed using data relating to wealth and income collected from
the late 19th to the early 20th century. But Piketty benefitted from a whole century of
extra data – right into the early 21st century. Using this wider pool of figures, Piketty
does two things. He argues that Kuznets’s data is misleading, because it was drawn from
what turns out to be a very unusual period of history. And he creates a theory he calls
the ‘central contradiction of capitalism’.
So what is this ‘central contradiction of capitalism’?
Throughout history, the annual rate of return on capital – which means the profits or
the interest you earn from investing your money –usually exceeds the annual growth
rate of the overall economy. Return on capital (or ‘r’) has remained relatively constant
– at around 5% - despite radical changes in who controls the capital – it’s generally
the rich and individuals who inherit it – and whether it’s held as gold, bonds, land or
in an investment portfolio.
In contrast to this, the annual growth of an economy (or ‘g’) has almost always
remained close to zero (it has only, in the last two centuries, reached a level of 1-2%).
There’s not much – short of revolution – that those individuals who rely solely
on labour to earn a living can do to change it.
Let me introduce Jane and Joe.
They both earn $100,000 a year. But Jane also has a $10million inheritance which she invests
annually in the stock market, earning a yearly return of 5%. Joe has no savings.
Let’s see how their incomes evolve.
Both Jane and Joe spend all of their annual salaries. After a year, Joe will have nothing
left over whereas Jane will have made $500,000 from her investments, which she reinvests.
Fast forward ten years…
Joe’s total wealth has grown very little – it depends on whether he is able to negotiate
a raise but – raise or no raise – Jane’s $10million has now grown to be worth more
than $16million – demonstrating Piketty’s argument that the difference in interest between
‘r’ and ‘g’ can lead to widening inequality over time. To avoid this, he proposes a global
tax on wealth that would effectively lower the rate of return on capital.
A more detailed examination can be found in the MACAT analysis.