Placeholder Image

字幕表 動画を再生する

  • In 1944, at the height of World War II, a British economist named Radford was serving

  • in the army. He was captured and lived in prison camps for more than a year. Prisoners

  • at the camps received Red Cross packages that contained food, cigarettes, and a few necessities.

  • These were precious supplies in POW camps. At first, prisoners gave away the things they

  • didn’t like, but before long they started trading instead. Radford’s explanation of

  • this behavior may surprise you. Very soon after capture people realized that it was

  • both undesirable and unnecessary in view of the limited size and the equality of supplies

  • to give away or to accept gifts of cigarettes or food.

  • Goodwill developed into trading as a more equitable means of maximizing individual satisfaction.”

  • More equitable? Really? Why would exchange be more equitable than gifts? Well, in a voluntary

  • exchange, both parties are better off, or they wouldn’t trade it all. Gifts are nice

  • but only the person receiving the gift is better off. Of course the giver might expect

  • a gift in return, but then, that’s exchange.

  • There are two reasons that this is important. Exchange corrects mistakes in allocation because

  • it moves stuff towards higher-valued uses. And exchange makes everyone who exchanges

  • a lot happier. There are two basic origins of exchange, and both are important.

  • First, same stuff different preferences. Let’s say we go on a field trip with boxed lunches

  • that each contain a sandwich, chips, pickle, and a cookie. I like chips and you like cookies.

  • I threw in my pickle to get you to agree, and we make the exchange. Were both happier

  • with our lunches even though were still dealing with the same amount of food overall.

  • Second, there’s same preferences, different stuff. Suppose I have apples and you have

  • oranges, but we both prefer eating fruit salad with the two mixed together. If we exchange,

  • then we can both have fruit salad. Were both happier with the same amount of fruit.

  • That’s remarkable.

  • In a world of scarce resources, each voluntary transaction means that people get happier

  • without any change to the total wealth that was available. That’s what makes trade so

  • powerful.

  • What if we have different stuff and different preferences? I do an exercise in class to

  • illustrate this. I give away T-shirts to my students, but I cheat. I make sure almost

  • every one of them ends up with the wrong size. So I ask, are you happy with your T-shirts?

  • Maybe 10 percent say that they are. Then I let them exchange shirts if they want to,

  • but only with their neighbors in the same row. Nonetheless, shirts move. You trade with

  • your neighbor, she trades with hers; the shirts travel around, improving the welfare of both

  • buyer and seller at every step. When it’s over, maybe 30 percent of the students are

  • happy with their shirt. It’s a big improvement but still not great.

  • Then I let people trade with anyone in the class. The class goes wild. Extra larges trade

  • for small, mediums for larges, and so on. It looks like chaos with people waving shirts,

  • calling out sizes. No plan, no direction, but at the end of trading, how many say theyre

  • happy? Ninety percent or more. The same number of shirts at the start, no one in charge,

  • and yet we went from 10 percent satisfied to 90 percent satisfied. Some of the shirts

  • changed hands many times. No one knew where the shirt was headedit just went. And everyone

  • who exchanged was happier. It seems like magic, but it’s just markets.

In 1944, at the height of World War II, a British economist named Radford was serving

字幕と単語

ワンタップで英和辞典検索 単語をクリックすると、意味が表示されます

B1 中級

なぜ物を交換するのか? (Why Do We Exchange Things?)

  • 132 10
    Ching Hung Lin に公開 2021 年 01 月 14 日
動画の中の単語