Placeholder Image

字幕表 動画を再生する

  • In pretty much all of the videos so far we've

  • been assuming an economic ideal, and that economic ideal

  • is perfect competition.

  • And perfect competition is exactly what

  • you think it is, competition.

  • But what I want to do in this video

  • is think about it in a little bit more exact terms,

  • in terms of what are the ground rules we need

  • to have to really have this ideal perfect competition.

  • It's important to realize that there's very few markets that

  • are truly perfectly competitive.

  • And those that are are very good for consumers,

  • but there are that get very close to being

  • perfectly competitive.

  • And if we have time, we will discuss those in this video.

  • Now, to be perfectly competitive,

  • you have to have many competitors.

  • So one of the first stipulations is many players.

  • And they need to be competing for the kind of the same buyer

  • and kind of offering the same thing.

  • And so they need to have identical products.

  • Remember, we're talking about an economic ideal here.

  • There's very few markets where the product is absolutely

  • identical or the service is absolutely identical,

  • but we're talking about an economic ideal over here.

  • The next condition you need is no barriers to entry.

  • So, if at any given moment it looks

  • attractive for other people to go into that market,

  • other people will go into that market

  • and there's nothing that's really going to stop them.

  • If the firms that are already in the market

  • are making an economic profit that means that it's good.

  • It's a good option for people to do.

  • You can do better in this market than your opportunity costs,

  • and so people will enter into that market.

  • And in order for this market to be perfectly competitive,

  • we can't have any barriers, nothing stopping those people.

  • On top of that, there can be no advantage

  • for established firms.

  • No advantage for existing firms.

  • So once someone jumps into the fray

  • and, assuming that they are somewhat competent,

  • they are going to be able to compete on kind of equal terms

  • with the people that are already there.

  • And then the last one, and this is important,

  • is that you have to have really good price information.

  • That the buyers and the sellers all

  • have to know about each other's prices.

  • The buyers need to know all the prices so that they can really

  • do good comparison shopping, and the sellers

  • need to know everyone's prices so that they can really

  • match prices really well.

  • So good price information.

  • Now, there are many different types

  • of markets that somewhat approximate

  • perfect competition.

  • There are very few that are completely purely

  • perfect competition.

  • But one of them that does come to mind, one of them that

  • does definitely come to mind is the US airline industry.

  • And the US airlines-- We can think

  • about these different bullet points,

  • how closely it matches it.

  • There are definitely many different airlines.

  • They don't offer identical products.

  • I'm sure the airlines would not agree.

  • They would say that they're differentiating

  • on their service and what type of food they give or, I guess,

  • don't give to you, or how much they're

  • charging for the baggage check-in and all the rest.

  • But for most consumers, they're just like, look,

  • I just want an economy class ticket

  • from San Francisco to New York, and they view them

  • as almost identical products.

  • So the airline industry does pretty well

  • on this first point.

  • No barriers to entry?

  • Well, there are some barriers to entry in the airline industry.

  • You need a few billion dollars that you

  • need to either find or borrow or whatever,

  • so that you can buy the capital so you

  • can start operating planes.

  • Or, I guess you could rent the planes.

  • But, either way, you need a lot of capital

  • to get into this business.

  • You need access to airport terminals

  • that you'll have to lease and landing

  • rights and all the rest.

  • So there are some barriers to entry.

  • But for the most part, at least in the United States,

  • if you are a US operator-- so there

  • are some barriers to entry, especially

  • for foreign operators.

  • But if you are a US operator and you have the capital

  • you will be able to be the next Virgin America or Southwest

  • Airlines or JetBlue.

  • So there are some barriers to entry, but they are low.

  • It's not like the government is saying

  • that no one else can start a new airlines.

  • No advantage for existing airlines?

  • Yeah.

  • That's somewhat true.

  • If I start a new airlines tomorrow

  • and it's offering comparable rates and comparable service,

  • I could imagine people would be willing to take this airlines.

  • So the airline industry seems pretty good there.

  • And good price information-- and this

  • is why the airline industry definitely came to my mind,

  • because I can't imagine an industry where you have better

  • price information that at least now, after the internet came

  • about-- than in the airline industry

  • you want a flight from San Francisco to New York,

  • you go to any of these travel sites, Orbits, Kayak,

  • Expedia, whatever you want to go to.

  • And you get all of the flights listed for you

  • and they're listed by price.

  • They consort them by price.

  • And you can actually pick-- and it's

  • known that people do this-- they pick a flight that

  • might be $500 or $600, but they can

  • compare based on a few pennies or even a few dollars.

  • So there's extremely good price information.

  • And, obviously, the sellers have all of their IT systems,

  • the airlines have all their IT systems

  • to keep track of where airline prices are going as well.

  • So the air travel industry, like most industries,

  • is not absolutely perfect competition,

  • but it gets pretty close to perfect competition.

  • And you even see that in the real world,

  • is that it's very hard for the airlines

  • to make really a lot of profit, whether you're

  • talking about accounting profit or even economic profit.

  • And you can see that from this supply and demand curve

  • right over here.

  • So on this axis, the horizontal axis, this is the quantity.

  • This is a measure of the quantity

  • of kind of airline service.

  • And we're measuring it in billions

  • of seat miles per week, and I know

  • that sounds like a strange thing.

  • But really, we're just saying, OK,

  • in a given week tell me all of the seats that are in use,

  • and multiply those number of seats--

  • so the seat miles in a given week.

  • The number of seats times the miles

  • or the average miles per seat in a given week,

  • and that gives you how much air travel.

  • This is a measure of air travel in, let's say, in the US

  • in that week.

  • And on this axis, this is the price.

  • This is price per, and this should actually

  • say price per seat mile.

  • And, of course, you have your supply curve right over here.

  • This is your supply curve.

  • At first, to start providing those first few miles.

  • The airlines are willing to do that relatively inexpensively.

  • Maybe they're finding that from the most obvious airports

  • that maybe the landing rights are cheaper

  • or it's cheaper to lease things, or whatever.

  • But as they start running more and more and more

  • routes, maybe between smaller and smaller cities, maybe

  • smaller and less efficient planes,

  • it starts to become more and more expensive for them

  • to supply those incremental miles.

  • And obviously, on the demand side,

  • if air travel is very, very expensive,

  • very few people are going to want to travel.

  • There is going to be very little travel that happens.

  • If it's very cheap, many people are going to want to travel.

  • Now, let's say that this is where the market is right now.

  • Obviously, we have an equilibrium price right

  • over there.

  • And then we have an equilibrium quantity of seat miles.

  • But let's say that the price level in order for the players

  • to actually have an economic profit is over here.

  • So it is right over here.

  • So this is the price needed for zero economic profit,

  • or you could say for neutral economic profit.

  • Or you could even say for normal profit,

  • for economic profit to be equal to zero.

  • So at that point, if that is the price, then

  • the firms that are offering airline travels,

  • they're kind of neutral between shutting down and continuing

  • to offer service.

  • But notice, the way I've drawn it here

  • that is substantially lower than the current equilibrium price.

  • So what this is saying is since the current equilibrium

  • price is a good bit higher than this,

  • or it's just higher at all, these firms in the market right

  • now are generating economic profit, definitely

  • positive economic profit.

  • So what's happening?

  • If there is positive economic profit,

  • that means that there's an incentive for other firms

  • to enter into this industry.

  • So what's going to happen is this

  • is going to be the supply curve right at that moment.

  • But as soon as another carrier realizes

  • that they can, or any of the carriers

  • realize they can offer more-- it doesn't even

  • have to be new carriers entering.

  • It could be existing carriers just offering, maybe buying

  • more planes or offering more routes.

  • Then maybe a little bit later the supply

  • curve shifts like this.

  • The supply curve shifts like that.

  • And then this would be our new equilibrium price.

  • But we're still making economic profit

  • because our new equilibrium price

  • is still higher than the price needed

  • for zero economic profit.

  • So still more people will continue to enter.

  • And so then you might have a new supply

  • curve that looks like this.

  • And now this is our new equilibrium price.

  • And notice what's happening.

  • We're traveling down to the right along the demand curve.

  • As more supply comes on, we are obviously

  • increasing the quantity and the price is going down.

  • But still, the equilibrium price is

  • higher than this line right over here.

  • So even more people will enter, until we

  • get to that point right over there.

  • And at that point, now the equilibrium price

  • is the price at which all of the players

  • are having zero economic profit.

  • And there's no incentive for more people

  • to enter into it, because then the equilibrium price will

  • go down, or they're, essentially right

  • now economic profit is zero.

  • So everyone is neutral in this scenario.

  • So I want to leave you there.

  • This is what happens with perfect competition.

  • That there's no barriers to entry

  • and more people go in and in and in, the price goes down,

  • the quantity will go up in this scenario.

  • But what I want to do in the next video

  • is to think about what if we didn't

  • have perfect competition.

  • And especially, what happens if we

  • have something like, I don't know,

  • something like a monopoly.

In pretty much all of the videos so far we've

字幕と単語

ワンタップで英和辞典検索 単語をクリックすると、意味が表示されます

A2 初級

完全競争|競争の形態|ミクロ経済学|カーンアカデミー (Perfect competition | Forms of competition | Microeconomics | Khan Academy)

  • 184 8
    Harrison Mia に公開 2021 年 01 月 14 日
動画の中の単語