Placeholder Image

字幕表 動画を再生する

  • So I got pulled into economics in 2007 because of the 2008 economic crisis. Mike Brown who

  • had been the first CFO of Microsoft, Chief Financial Officer of Microsoft and treasurer

  • of Microsoft, he came to Toronto in 2007 and took my wife and I out to dinner and said

  • he was trying to put together a research group to work on economics and he would like me

  • to be involved. And I said, "I don't know anything about economics." And he said, "That's

  • okay because nobody does and the whole system is about to collapse." He said, "The balance

  • sheets of all the big investment banks -- it's like they have cancer. They're full of holes."

  • And I remember being very struck by this because this was before anybody was talking about

  • this.

  • And so I started to meet with a group of people that he was pulling together to understand

  • what was gonna happen and to understand if there was any way to save the situation. It

  • was a very ambitious thing and, of course, we failed. But along the way I was motivated

  • as a kind of public service to get interested in economics.

  • And what I found . . . economics, in a way, is very easy for a physicist to understand

  • because it's very mathematical. And the mathematical models that they use are very clean. They're

  • based on assumptions and hypotheses, and you can study them. And as I studied it I began

  • to understand, some for myself and more from just reading around because the faults with

  • the standard economic models, with the standard models of finance, are well known. They have

  • been in the literature for decades and decades. So let me give some examples.

  • The standard model of economics is called the neoclassical model and it assumes that

  • markets or systems where trading happens between consumers and firms and there's certain simple

  • models of how that goes on. And the ideas that these come to equilibrium. Equilibrium

  • not in the physical sense but in special economic sense in which you reach a point at which

  • the prices are fixed such that market forces fix the prices such that you maximize the

  • happiness of the consumers and maximize the profits of the firms. And in so called equilibrium

  • nobody can become happier or more profitable without somebody else becoming less happy

  • or less profitable. And the ideology behind this -- not behind the mathematics because

  • mathematics doesn't have an ideology -- but behind the arguments that were made and still

  • are made from this model is that markets don't need regulation because they have these natural

  • equilibria where everybody benefits to the maximum possible. And if you're in equilibrium

  • you can't do better.

  • Now there's a fault with this and it's an obvious fault and it's been known since the

  • 1970s from some theorems proved by some economists including some of the founders of this field

  • of mathematical economics, which is that there's not one equilibrium, there are many equilibria.

  • In fact, there's a vast number of equilibria. And so which equilibria, even assuming that

  • this is a decent model of the economy which is not clear, but even assuming it's a good

  • model, which equilibria you're in depends on the past history, it depends on regulation,

  • it depends on politics, it depends on taste, it depends on changing taste, changing preferences.

  • And so history matters and what's called path dependence matters.

  • This takes us outside the neoclassical model of economics but it doesn't take us outside

  • of economics because some wiser economist, for example, Brian Arthur had for years been

  • developing models and theories of path dependent economy where the history does matter. People

  • from the area of complex systems like Stu Kauffman, Prubac in developing models of markets

  • where the history matters, where there's not a single equilibrium, where there are many

  • equilibria. And where change is paramount.

  • Another symptom of this is the idea that arbitrage isn't, I mean, in these neoclassical models

  • when you go to equilibrium, arbitrage is impossible. Arbitrage is making a profit from trading

  • around a circle of goods or a circle of currencies without actually producing anything. And in

  • equilibrium that's supposed to be impossible but lots of firms and investment banks made

  • fortunes off of currency trading, so why is that? It turns out because you're never really

  • at equilibrium.

  • So why is the notion of equilibrium so powerful? I think part of the answer is this idea of

  • physics envy, that economists thought that what they're doing was more scientific, hence

  • more correct, if it looked like physics. And physics had this timeless picture in which

  • what really mattered, as we were saying before, is the whole history of the system. And in

  • physics there's also a big notion of coming to equilibrium which is, although however,

  • it's important to say, a different notion of equilibrium. And somehow people in economics

  • got seduced into this model which again works in the small -- if you have a small little

  • corner of the economy, a small market -- it may work for a while to characterize approximately

  • what's going on. Arbitrage is not always there. It's not always, I mean, arbitrage, arbitrage

  • does get eaten up. There are market forces which do push you towards equilibria. There's

  • some truth in it.

  • But the whole thing is a disaster if I can say that as an outsider. And it led indirectly

  • -- it wasn't the only reason why regulations were lifted on markets and trading through

  • the decades, but when people were making arguments to Congress, to the President's office that

  • the economy would be better off without regulation, this was the "scientific rationale for it"

  • and led to the very unstable situation of the last economic crisis.

  • And indeed there's still a very dangerous and unstable situation in the world economy

  • because -- well, I'm not an economist. I'm not gonna pontificate about the problems in

  • the economy, but one could see how the idea of timelessness gave false comfort to an unsuccessful

  • scientific theory in the realm of economics.

So I got pulled into economics in 2007 because of the 2008 economic crisis. Mike Brown who

字幕と単語

ワンタップで英和辞典検索 単語をクリックすると、意味が表示されます

B1 中級

イ・スモリン:物理学の妬みと経済理論 (Lee Smolin: Physics Envy and Economic Theory)

  • 85 16
    姚姚 に公開 2021 年 01 月 14 日
動画の中の単語